Marginal product of labor
Encyclopedia
In economics, the marginal product of labor also known as MPL (or MPN if N is number of labor units) is the change in output that result from employing an added unit of labor. More generally, in defining marginal product, other inputs to production are held constant. Then the marginal product of a given input X can be expressed as relative to output Y as:
MP = ΔYX = (the change of Y)/(the change of X).

Marginal Product of Labor is not simply the additional output produced by the last worker hired

In the short run the only way a firm can vary production is by changing the quantity of variable input. The variable input is conventionally assumed to be labor. Output is referred to as the product of labor. The total product of labor is the amount of output produced. The total product curve is the short run relationship between the amount of output produced and the quantity of labor used. Capital which is fixed serves as a capacity constraint. Marginal product of labor is the slope of the total product curve. Marginal product is the increase in output resulting from an incremental increase in the amount of labor employed. Increasing the amount of an input while holding other factors of production constant affects the efficiency of the entire production process. The effects can be either positive or negative. Typically, at low levels of production, increases in the variable input have positive effects due to specialization of labor. In these early stages each additional unit of labor produces more output than did the previous unit of labor. Thus the marginal product of labor is increasing. Graphically the total product curve is increasing and getting steeper as units of labor are added. At some point the additional units of labor begin to interfere with the productivity of all other units of labor being employed - people are getting into each other’s way. The result is that the average product of labor falls. This disruption to productivity gets worse as more units of labor are added. During this range of production, total product is still increasing but each successive addition is smaller (the marginal product of labor is falling). The curve is still rising but it is becoming flatter. The point at which this change in the shape of the total product curve occurs (from getting steeper to getting flatter) is called the point of diminishing marginal returns. Beyond this point additions to output due to a unit increase in labor are successively smaller.

The point that the marginal product of labor is not the addition to output directly attributable to the marginal unit is well stated in the following paragraph:


[I]t is important to underline that the marginal product is not, properly speaking, the contribution of the marginal unit by itself….The second man may very well produce nine or ten or eleven and still the total output increases only to eighteen because the first man reduces his output to nine, or eight or seven in the presence of the second. In our example, output increases from ten bushels to eighteen bushels when one adds the second man not because the second man only adds eight, but rather because his presence on the field makes the situation such that the total output of both men is eighteen. Notice that the contribution per man is reduced: the average product is actually nine. This may very well be how much each of the two laborers contributes. But this is not what interests us: what we wish to note is that by adding the second man, output was increased by eight. Thus, the marginal product of the second man is eight. But his actual contribution may be very different than this.

Examples

  1. There is a factory which produces toys. When there are no workers in the factory, no toys are produced. When there is one worker in the factory, six toys are produced per hour. When there are two workers in the factory, eleven toys are produced per hour. There is a marginal product of labor of 5 when there are two workers in the factory compared to one. When the marginal product of labor is positive, this is called increasing marginal returns. However, as the number of workers increases, the marginal product of labor may not increase indefinitely. When not scaled
    Scaled
    Scaled may mean:* Scaled Composites , formerly the Rutan Aircraft Factory* Scaled Aviation Industries of Lahore, Pakistan, a Light Sports Aircraft Manufacturer...

     properly, the marginal product of labor may go down when the number of employees goes up, creating a situation known as diminishing marginal returns.When the marginal product of labor becomes negative, it is known as negative marginal returns.

Deriving the marginal product of a factor of production from the production function

  • Assume that the production process involves three inputs x, y and z.

  • The production function is Q = 2x2+3xy + 6.45y2+1.75yz +0.35z3. The marginal product of a factor of production is the partial derivative of that function with respect to the specific input.

MPx= 4x +3y

MPy= 3x + 12.90y +1.75z

MPz= 1.75y + 1.05z2

Definitions

The marginal product of labor is the change in output per unit change in labor. In discrete terms the marginal product of labor is ∆Q/∆L. In marginal terms the MPL is the first derivative of the total product curve or short run production function or ∂Q/∂L. The precise mathematical formula is MPL = (dAPL/dL)q + APL. Graphically the MPL is the slope of the total product curve/short run production function.

MPL and MC

The marginal product of labor is directly related to costs of production. Cost are divided between fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are costs that relate to the fixed input, capital, or rK where r is the rate of return and K is the quantity of capital. Variable costs are the costs of the variable input, labor, or wL where w is the wage rate and L is the amount of labor employed. Thus VC = wL . MC is the change in total cost per unit change in output or ∆C/∆Q. In the short run, production can be varied only by changing the variable input. Thus only variable costs change as output increases ∆C = ∆VC = ∆Lw. Marginal costs is ∆Lw/∆Q. Now, ∆L/∆Q is the reciprocal of the marginal product of labor (∆Q/∆L). Therefore, marginal cost is simply the wage rate w divided by the marginal product of labor
MC = ∆VC∕∆q;
∆VC = w∆L;
∆L∕∆q the change in quantity of labor to affect a one unit change in output = 1∕MPL.
Therefore MC = w ∕ MPL


Thus if the marginal product of labor is rising then marginal costs will be falling and if the marginal product of labor is falling marginal costs will be rising.(assuming a constant wage rate).

Relation between MPL and APL

The average product of labor is the total product of labor divided by the number of units of labor employed or Q/L. The average product of labor is a common measure of labor productivity. The APL curve is shaped like an inverted “u”. At low production levels the APL tends to increases as additional labor is added. The primary reason for the increase is specialization and division of labor. At the point the APL reaches its maximum value APL equals the MPL. Beyond this point the APL falls.

During the early stages of production MPL is greater than APL. When the MPL is above the APL the APL will increase. Eventually the MPL reaches it maximum value at the point of diminishing returns. Beyond this point MPL will decrease. However, at the point of diminishing returns the MPL is still above the APL and APL will continue to increase until MPL equals APL. When MPL is below APL, APL will decrease.

Graphically the APL curve can be derived from the total product curve by drawing secants from the origin that intersect (cut) the total product curve. The slope of the secant line equals the average product of labor (Slope = dQ/dL). The slope of the curve at each intersection marks a point on the average product curve. The slope increases until the line reaches a point of tangency with the total product curve. This point marks the maximum average product of labor. It also marks the point where MPL (which is the slope of the total product curve) equals the APL (the slope of the secant). Beyond this point the slope of the secants become progressively smaller as APL declines. The MPL curve intersects the APL curve from above at the maximum point of the APL curve. Thereafter, the MPL curve is below the APL curve.

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns

The falling MPL is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns. The law states,”as units of one input are added (with all other inputs held constant) a point will be reached where the resulting additions to output will begin to decrease; that is marginal product will decline.” The law of diminishing marginal returns applies regardless of whether the production function exhibits increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale. The key factor is that the variable input is being changed while all other factors of production are being held constant. Under such circumstances diminishing marginal returns are inevitable at some level of production.

Diminishing marginal returns differs from diminishing returns. Diminishing marginal returns means that the marginal product of the variable input is falling. Diminishing returns occur when the marginal product of the variable input is negative. That is when a unit increase in the variable input causes total product to fall. At the point that diminishing returns begin the MPL is zero.

MPL, MRPL and Profit Maximization

The general rule is that firm maximizes profit by producing that quantity of output where marginal revenue equals marginal costs. The profit maximization issue can also be approached from the input side. That is, what is the profit maximizing usage of the variable input? To maximize profits the firm should increase usage "up to the point where the input’s marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs". So mathematically the profit maximizing rule is MRPL = MCL The marginal profit per unit of labor equals the marginal revenue product of labor minus the marginal cost of labor or MπL = MRPL - MCLA firm maximizes profits where MπL = 0.

The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue per unit change in the variable input assume labor. That is MRPL = ∆TR/∆L. MRPL is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labor or MRPL = MR x MPL.
  • Derivation:
MR = ∆TR/∆Q
MPL = ∆Q/∆L
MRPL = MR x MPL = (∆TR/∆Q) x (∆Q/∆L) = ∆TR/∆L

Example

  • Assume that production function is Q = 90L - L2

• MCL = 30

• Output price is $40 per unit.
MPL = 90 - 2L
MRPL = 40(90 - 2L)
MRPL = 3600 - 80L
MRPL = MCL (Profit Max Rule)
3600 - 80L = 30

"3570 = 80L
L = 44.625
44.625 is the profit maximizing number of workers.
Q = 90L - L2
Q = 90(44.625) - (44.625)2
Q= 4016.25 - 89.25
Q = 3927
The profit maximizing output is 3927 units

• And the profit is
TR - TC = π
π = 40(3927) - 30(3927)
Π = 157,080 - 117,810
π = 39,270

Marginal productivity ethics

In the aftermath of the marginal revolution
Marginal Revolution
Marginal Revolution is a blog focused on economics run by economists Tyler Cowen and Alex Tabarrok, both of whom teach at George Mason University. The blog's slogan is "Small steps toward a much better world." The site is updated daily and focuses on current events and newly released reports or books...

 in economics, a number of economists including John Bates Clark
John Bates Clark
John Bates Clark was an American neoclassical economist. He was one of the pioneers of the marginalist revolution and opponent to the Institutionalist school of economics, and spent most of his career teaching at Columbia University.-Biography:Clark was born and raised in Providence, Rhode...

 and T.N. Carver sought to derive an ethical theory of income distribution based on the idea that workers were morally entitled to receive a wage exactly equal to their marginal product. In the 20th century, marginal productivity ethics found few supporters among economists, being criticised not only by egalitarians but by economists associated with the Chicago school
Chicago school
Chicago school may refer to:* Chicago school * Chicago school * Chicago school * Chicago school * Chicago school * Chicago School of Professional Psychology...

 such as Frank Knight
Frank Knight
Frank Hyneman Knight was an American economist who spent most of his career at the University of Chicago, where he became one of the founders of the Chicago school. Nobel laureates James M. Buchanan, Milton Friedman and George Stigler were all students of Knight at Chicago. Knight supervised...

 (in The Ethics of Competition) and the Austrian School, such as Leland Yeager http://oll.libertyfund.org/?option=com_staticxt&staticfile=show.php%3Ftitle=1663&chapter=37668&layout=html&Itemid=27. However, marginal productivity ethics were defended by George Stigler
George Stigler
George Joseph Stigler was a U.S. economist. He won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1982, and was a key leader of the Chicago School of Economics, along with his close friend Milton Friedman....

.

See also

  • Marginal product
    Marginal product
    In economics and in particular neoclassical economics, the marginal product or marginal physical product of an input is the extra output that can be produced by using one more unit of the input , assuming that the quantities of no other inputs to production...

  • Marginal revenue
    Marginal revenue
    In microeconomics, marginal revenue is the extra revenue that an additional unit of product will bring. It is the additional income from selling one more unit of a good; sometimes equal to price...

  • Diminishing marginal returns
  • Increasing marginal returns
  • Average marginal return
The source of this article is wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.  The text of this article is licensed under the GFDL.
 
x
OK