Intertemporal choice
Encyclopedia
Intertemporal choice is the study of the relative value people assign to two or more payoffs at different points in time. Most choices require decision-makers to trade-off costs and benefits at different points in time. These decisions maybe about savings, work effort, education, nutrition, exercise, health care and so forth. For nearly 80 years, economists have analyzed intertemporal decisions using the discounted utility (DU) model, which assumes that people evaluate the pleasures and pains resulting from a decision in much the same way that financial markets evaluate losses and gains, exponentially ‘discounting’ the value of outcomes according to how delayed they are in time. DU has been used to describe how people actually make intertemporal choices and it has been used as a tool for public policy. Policy decisions about how much to spend on research and development, health and education all depend on the discount rate used to analyze the decision.

The Keynesian consumption function was based on two major hypothesis. Firstly, marginal propensity to consume lies between 0 and 1. Secondly, average propensity to consume falls as income rises. The early empirical studies were consistent with these hypothesis. However, after the World War II it was observed that savings did not rise as incomes rose. The Keynesian model therefore, failed to explain the consumption phenomenon and thus emerged the theory of Intertemporal Choice. Intertemporal choice was introduced by John Rae
John Rae (economist)
John Rae , was a Scottish/Canadian economist. His most famous work was the Statement of Some New Principles on the Subject of Political Economy.-Sources:...

 in 1834 in the "Sociological Theory of Capital".Later, Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk
Eugen Ritter von Böhm-Bawerk was an Austrian economist who made important contributions to the development of the Austrian School of economics.-Biography:...

 in 1889 and Irving Fisher
Irving Fisher
Irving Fisher was an American economist, inventor, and health campaigner, and one of the earliest American neoclassical economists, though his later work on debt deflation often regarded as belonging instead to the Post-Keynesian school.Fisher made important contributions to utility theory and...

 in 1930 elaborated on the model. A few other models based on intertemporal choice include the Life Cycle Income Hypothesis proposed by Modigiliani and the Permanent Income Hypothesis proposed by Friedman. The concept of Walrasian Equilibrium maybe also be extended to incorporate intertemporal choice. The Walrasian analysis of such an equilibrium introduces two "new" concepts of prices: futures prices and spot prices.

Fisher's Model of Intertemporal Consumption

Irving Fisher developed the theory of Intertemporal Choice in 1930 in his book 'Theory of interest'. Contrary to Keynes, who related consumption to current income, Fisher’s model showed how rational forward looking consumers chooses consumption for the present and future to maximize their lifetime satisfaction.
According to Fisher, an individual's impatience depends on four characteristics of his income stream: the size, the time shape, the composition and risk. Besides this foresight, self control, habit, expectation of life, bequest motive (or concern for lives of others) and habit are the six personal factors that determine a person's impatience which in turn determines his time preference.
In order to understand the choice exercised by a consumer across different periods of time we take consumption in one period as a composite commodity. Suppose there is one consumer, N commodities, and two periods. Preferences are given by U (x1; x2) where
xt = (xt1; :::; xtN ). Income in period t is Yt. Savings in period 1 is S1, spending in period t is Ct, and r is the interest rate.

C1 + S1 ≤Y1 ... (1)

C2 ≤ Y2 + S1 (1 + r) ... (2)

We arrive at the following equation from equation 1 and 2

= ... (3)

The left hand side shows the present value expenditure and right hand side depicts the present value income respectively. Multiplying the equation by (1+r) gives us the future value.

Now the consumer has to choose a C1 and C2 such that
Max U(C1,C2)
subject to
C1+C2/(1+r) = Y1 + Y2/(1+r)

A consumer maybe a net saver or a net borrower. If he's initially at a level of consumption where he's neither of the above(i.e. a net borrower or net saver), an increase in income may make him a net saver or a net borrower depending on his preferences. An increase in current income or future income will increase current and future consumption(consumption smoothing motives).

Now, let us consider a scenario where the interest rates are increased. If the consumer is a net saver, he will save more in the current period due to the substitution effect and consume more in the current period due to the income effect. The net effect thus, becomes ambiguous. If the consumer is a net borrower, however, he will tend to consume less in the current period due to the substitution effect and income effect thereby reducing his overall current consumption.

Modigiliani's Life Cycle Income Hypothesis

The Life Cycle Hypothesis is based on the following model:

max Ut = ΣL[U(Ct)(1+δ)-t]

subject to

ΣLCt(1+r)-t = ΣNYt(1+r)-t + Wo

U(Ct): satisfaction received from consumption in time period 't'

Ct:level of consumption,

Yt: income

δ: rate of time preference ( a measure of individual preference between present and future activity)

Wo: initial level of income producing assets

Typically, a person’s MPC(marginal propensity to consume) is relatively high during young adulthood, decreases during the middle-age years, and increases when the person is near or in retirement. The Life Cycle Hypothesis(LCH) model defines individual behavior as an attempt to smooth out consumption patterns over one's lifetime somewhat independent of current levels of income. This model states that early in one's life consumption expenditure may very well exceed income as the individual may be making major purchases related to buying a new home, starting a family, and beginning a career. At this stage in life the individual will borrow from the future to support these expenditure needs. In mid-life however, these expenditure patterns begin to level off and are supported or perhaps exceeded by increases in income.
At this stage the individual repays any past borrowings and begins to save for her or his retirement.
Upon retirement, consumption expenditure may begin to decline however income usually declines dramatically. In this stage of life, the individual dis-saves or lives off past savings until death.
 

Friedman's Permanent Income Hypothesis

After the Second World War, it was noticed that a model in which current consumption was just a function of current income clearly too simplistic. It could not explain the fact that the long-run average propensity to consume seemed to be roughly constant despite the marginal propensity to consume being much lower. Friedman's Permanent Income Hypothesis are one of the models which seeks to explain this apparent contradiction.

According to the Permanent Income Hypothesis, permanent consumption, CP, is proportional to permanent income, YP. Permanent income is a subjective notion of likely medium-run future income. Permanent consumption is a similar notion of consumption.

Actual consumption, C, and actual income, Y, consist of these permanent components plus unanticipated transitory components, CT and YT, respectively.


CPt2YPt


Ct = CPt + CPt


Yt = YPt + YPt

Hyperbolic Discounting

The article so far has considered cases where individuals make intertemporal choices by considering the present discounted value of their consumption and income. Every period in the future is exponentially discounted with the same interest rate. A different class of economists, however, argue that individuals are often affected by what is called the temporal myopia. The consumer's typical response to uncertainty in this case is to sharply reduce the importance of the future of their decision making.This effect is called hyperbolic discounting
Hyperbolic discounting
In behavioral economics, hyperbolic discounting is a time-inconsistent model of discounting.Given two similar rewards, humans show a preference for one that arrives sooner rather than later. Humans are said to discount the value of the later reward, by a factor that increases with the length of the...

. In the common tongue it reflects the sentiment “Eat, drink and be merry, for tomorrow we may die.”

Mathematically, it may be represented as follows:



where,


f(D):discount factor,
D: delay in the reward,
k:parameter governing the degree of discounting

When choosing between $100 or $110 a day later,individuals may want to wait a day for an extra $10. Yet after a month passes, many of these people will reverse their preferences and now choose the immediate $100 rather than wait a day for an additional $10.

See also

  • intertemporal consumption
    Intertemporal consumption
    Economic theories of intertemporal consumption seek to explain people's preferences in relation to consumption and saving over the course of their life...

  • Temporal discounting
    Temporal discounting
    Temporal discounting refers to the tendency of people to discount rewards as they approach a temporal horizon in the future or the past . To put it another way, it is a tendency to give greater value to rewards as they move away from their temporal horizons and towards the "now"...

  • Discounted utility
    Discounted utility
    Discounted utility is an economics term in which economists, accountants, underwriters, and other financial analysts include the future discounted value of a good in its present value...

  • Decision theory
    Decision theory
    Decision theory in economics, psychology, philosophy, mathematics, and statistics is concerned with identifying the values, uncertainties and other issues relevant in a given decision, its rationality, and the resulting optimal decision...

The source of this article is wikipedia, the free encyclopedia.  The text of this article is licensed under the GFDL.
 
x
OK